Land-use change is a human decision. An actor evaluates economical and physical
characteristics of a piece of land before deciding how to use it. Rationally the actor should choose a course
of action in his/her own best financial interest. The choice may not always be in the best
interest of the society as a whole or even the world. Examples like
deforestation, climate change, erosion, and degradation can be seen as
individuals not valuing environmental services provided by landscapes and
instead looking toward individual economic benefits. In what ways can environmental services be
incorporated into the decision-making process of individuals is a question that
has not yet fully been addressed.
Environmental services are the conditions and processes in
the natural ecosystems that function in sustaining human life (Daily, 1997;
Zhang et al., 2007). Today,
environmental services are mostly unrecognized and taken for granted. This has
resulted from a framework of thinking that the environment is something that
must be conquered and disservices mitigated.
Disservices like pests and weeds impacting agricultural systems (Zhang
et al., 2007) or flooding and fire that impact our built environments. Conquering the environment has led to more
resource extraction and land productivity, fueling development and the modern
economy. The unattended consequence of
modifying the environment is that the services provided by it have also been
destroyed. Services like carbon pools, water supply, soil conservation, and
biodiversity. People have reached a
level of development where smart sustainable approaches are needed, ones that
continue development while amplifying environmental services and mitigating disservices.
The case study of the educational trust Kamehameha Schools development
plan offers insight into land-use decisions that integrate environmental
services into planning (see Goldstein et al., 2012). Their case shows a notable
gap between the environmental services for society and the economic benefit
(Goldstein et al., 2012). The best
economic return would have been to sell for commercial development. The organization with long historic roots and
prominent role in the community had to use moral values when choosing
development options. This was the
motivation in developing with environmental services in mind, but the question
of not developing also shows a problem with the current economic system. If
they chose the path of conservation, not developing at all, they would have had
to continue to pay taxes on the land meaning an economic loss. In there own interests they must develop. Valuing
environmental series can change the calculation. At very least not taxing land providing
services would have relieved economic pressures to develop. At best giving some sort of payment for
environmental services would have led to a positive force at preserving the
land. The current economic system
required them to make tradeoffs, find ways to develop while preserving as much
environmental services as possible.
What is needed is changes in how environmental services are
valued. Much attention has been applied
to valuing environmental services (Zhang et al., 2007; Ninan & Inoue, 2013),
but it is impossible to know what the true economic value of these services are
since they are not accounted for in economic decisions. Furthermore the biophysical aspects of environmental
services are still not fully cataloged.
These services are taken for granted, much like the sun is assumed to
continue to shine, the environment is assumed always to operate. The
environment is not like the sun, it is close to us and people modify it. Moving forward as a global society we must
look to development that takes into account the full impact. We still have not seen the full consequences
of our current development paradigm.
Development is projected to grow at an alarming rate in the global
tropics (Seto et al., 2012). This offers
both a challenge and an opportunity. The
challenge is not to develop in business as usual approaches, which can have
devastating impacts on global carbon pools and biodiversity hotspots. The opportunity is to find market solutions
that will prompt sustainable development and stewardship of the
environment. Now that people have shown
they can modify the environment towards economic benefits, they need to show
that they can modify it to social and environmental benefits as well. When we do that we will have a development
paradigm for the future.
Works Cited
Daily, G., (1997). Nature's Services. Island Press,
Washington, DC.
Goldstein, J. H., Caldarone, G., Duarte, T. K., Ennaanay,
D., Hannahs, N., Mendoza, G., ... & Daily, G. C. (2012). Integrating
ecosystem-service tradeoffs into land-use decisions. Proceedings of the
National Academy of Sciences,109(19), 7565-7570.
Ninan, K. N., & Inoue, M. (2013). Valuing forest
ecosystem services: What we know and what we don't. Ecological
Economics, 93, 137-149.
Seto, K. C., Güneralp, B., & Hutyra, L. R. (2012).
Global forecasts of urban expansion to 2030 and direct impacts on biodiversity
and carbon pools. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 109(40),
16083-16088.
Zhang, W., Ricketts, T. H., Kremen, C., Carney, K., &
Swinton, S. M. (2007). Ecosystem services and dis-services to
agriculture. Ecological economics,64(2), 253-260.